Lessons from the Derecho: When Industry Self-Regulation Is Not Enough
Lessons from the Derecho: When Industry Self-Regulation Is Not Enough
Lessons from the Derecho: When Industry Self-Regulation Is Not Enough

    Get Involved Today

    The FCC released a fairly thorough report on the
    widespread 9-1-1 failure that followed the June 2012 “derecho” windstorm. For
    those who don’t remember, the derecho differs from most weather events by
    coming up almost without warning. According to the report, carriers had
    approximately two hours of warning from the time the derecho started in the
    Ohio Valley to when it hit the D.C. Metro region.

    As a consequence of the damage done by the derecho, Northern
    Virginia experienced a massive failure of its 9-1-1 network, leaving over 1
    million people with working phones (at least in some places) but no access to
    9-1-1.  West Virginia experienced
    systemic problems as well, as a did a scattering of locations in other states
    impacted by the derecho. Verizon maintains the network in Northern Virginia,
    while West Virginia is managed by Frontier.

    In both cases, the report concluded that both Verizon and
    Frontier failed to follow industry best practices or their own internal
    procedures. To be clear, this was not a massive dereliction of duty. But the
    accumulation of some corner cutting over here, some poor practice over there,
    meant that when the unpredicted crisis hit the system suffered critical
    failures precisely when most needed. Unlike just about every other part of the
    network, where providers balance the cost of hardening a network against
    potential events with a number of other factors, the core 9-1-1 system is
    explicitly supposed to remain operational in even the most extraordinary
    circumstances.  It is the foundation of
    public access to emergency services. As long as I can contact the phone
    network, I should be able to get 9-1-1 service. Public safety responders rely
    on the public reporting emergencies so that they can efficiently deploy
    resources as much as the public depends on its ability to contact emergency
    services through 9-1-1.

    It is particularly shocking to see this happen with Verizon.
    As I’ve observed before, Verizon generally prides itself on maintaining a
    high-quality network. Customer satisfaction surveys generally agree with this
    self-assessment. It is part of Verizon’s overall business strategy: build the
    best network, attract the customers willing to pay a premium for it. Yes, part
    of that strategy means selling off or generally neglecting the copper footprint
    outside the FIOS territories. But the 9-1-1 failure occurred in Northern
    Virginia, precisely the kind of high rate-of-return territory Verizon targets
    for top-of-the-line service. So what happened?

    What happened in the derecho illustrates the problem of
    relying on general incentives and industry best practices instead of regulation
    for critical safety and reliability issues. In understanding this lesson, we
    need to understand that it is not that Verizon (or Frontier, or other
    companies) are evil or greedy or callous or any of the other delightful
    adjectives people like to use to personalize this. It’s not. Verizon and
    Frontier understand about keeping 9-1-1 going just fine. They are all for it.
    They are part of the group that develops the industry best practices, which
    they supplement with their own internal procedures.

    Nevertheless, in economic terms, maintaining 9-1-1 is a
    deadweight cost of doing business. Expenditures on 9-1-1 do not contribute to
    the bottom line in the way fiber deployment or spectrum acquisitions do.
    Maintaining the 9-1-1 system is essentially a “public safety tax.” Yes, they
    get to recover the expenses in a general way through fees tacked on to the
    phone bill. But when deciding whether to spend a dollar more on 9-1-1 or how
    carefully to follow industry best practices rather than cut corners, the
    rational network operator has plenty of countervailing incentive at the margin
    to divert that dollar from 9-1-1 to something that contributes to the bottom
    line, or to push off some recommended maintenance just a little bit, or
    otherwise cut a few corners here and there.

    The other important lesson is that, when dealing with
    emergency services in extreme conditions, it takes relatively few errors to
    have potentially far reaching impact. This makes 9-1-1 even more expensive to
    maintain. What can pass as a reasonable practice in managing a giant enterprise
    like Verizon’s telephone system is unacceptable in 9-1-1. Since all humans make
    errors from time to time, this means additional checks and redundancies (and
    workers). Again, while carriers have plenty of generic incentive to make sure their 9-1-1 systems remain intact, but
    for any specific decision about
    investing resources, the line worker or manager will invariably weigh the cost
    against much more attractive alternatives.

     

    Regulation Comes In
    Where Industry Standards Are Not Enough

    Regulation and enforcement change the incentive equation at
    the margin. First, in a behavioral way, making a rule mandatory and putting in
    an enforcement and monitoring structure generally make people take the
    requirements more seriously. To take an every day example, we all have
    incentive to drive carefully. We still have posted speed limits, because that
    sets an expectation about what it actually means to drive carefully.  We have enforcement and penalties, because
    otherwise people decide to let their own judgment about what’s safe be their
    guide.

    The other rather direct way it alters incentive is that it
    increases the direct cost of not making the investment. To use the speed limits
    analogy, I may still decide to go 50 in a 30 MPH zone because I’m in a rush and
    decide to risk it. But I’m a lot less likely to do it in a photo-enforcement
    zone and where the fine is doubled for going more than 15 miles above the speed
    limit.

    In looking at the lessons from the derecho, we need to
    recognize that “industry has incentive to do X” is often not enough. In
    particular, in the case of emergency and reliability requirements for networks,
    we need to recognize that the general incentive of carriers to make sure their
    network stays up in a crisis doesn’t guarantee the industry will do what they
    need to do, because industry participants also
    have incentive to spend that money on things that more directly contribute to
    the bottom line.

    That has several immediate implications. First, the FCC needs to make sure that all carriers are up to standard on 9-1-1, especially those carriers that actually maintain the 9-1-1 network rather than simply route 9-1-1 calls to the network. As I said above, Verizon and Frontier are not uniquely bad actors. Odds are good that every carrier — while generally compliant and taking their 9-1-1 obligations seriously, has similarly cut a few corners or neglected a few procedures here and there. Why? Because they all have the same incentives. A few spot inspections to make sure every carrier is on top of things will help prevent any similar 9-1-1 failures elsewhere.

    Longer term, as the FCC considers both the response to Hurricane Sandy and the future of the phone network, we need to carefully consider where we need to rely on regulation rather than on industry incentives and self-regulation. That certainly applies to 9-1-1, but it also applies to network reliability generally. No network wants off time for any reason. But that does not gaurantee that carriers will find the right trade off between cost and benefit that we as a nation need in order to have a reliable infrastructure. When our broadband networks go down, it is more than an inconvenience. It disrupts business and disrupts people’s lives. Carriers have incentive to minimize dowtime, but they have other incentives as well. We need federal and state agencies to be willing to push carriers to spend that extra dollar when it’s needed, even if they would rather spend it on something else.

    In short, Commissioner Rosenworcel is spot on in her statement when she says “it is time for an honest accounting of the resiliency of our
    Nation’s network infrastructure in the digital and wireless age.” That starts
    with recognizing that actual, enforceable rules with real teeth are necessary
    to make sure that core emergency functions work properly. General incentives
    are all well and good, but for critical emergency functions, they are simply not good enough.